A recently published
analysis by Thomas L. Hungerford (see highlights below) looks at factors
driving the growth of income inequality for the period between 1991 to
2006. Hungerford looked at the
contributing impact of three factors, tax policy, labor wages and capital
income. During the studied period he found that capital income (capital gains,
interest income, business income and dividends) was by far the largest factor contributing
to rising income inequality. Wages and salaries alone were not a factor and tax
policies were only a minor contributor during this period, largely due to the
more favorable tax treatment of capital gains.
This report doesn’t trace
the history of income inequality prior to 1991 where changes in wage growth in
the late 1970’s and the collapsing of upper income tax brackets in 1980 and
1985 were more dramatic.
It is worth remembering that
for most of the past 100 years capital gains was treated as ordinary income for
tax purposes. In recent times, capital
gains have be treated as a separate class of income with a more favorable tax
treatment. Capital ownership has always been more concentrated at the upper end
of the income/wealth continuum. Capital
is, of course, an ownership stake in our economy whether through stocks, bonds,
property or business ownership. The income generated when these capital
investments are bought and sold is currently taxed at 15% (if it is held for
more than a year). That is less than half the top tax rate for wages and
salaries. And how is capital ownership
distributed in America ?
Who
Owns What In America ?
The distribution of wealth ownership, as opposed to income inequality, is even more skewed towards the wealthy as the pie chart below shows. The whole pie represents the total wealth inAmerica . Each of the five slices of the pie represent
20% of the US population according to how much wealth they own.
The distribution of wealth ownership, as opposed to income inequality, is even more skewed towards the wealthy as the pie chart below shows. The whole pie represents the total wealth in
The slice of ownership
for the poor and working poor are barely visible. Eighty-percent of all
Americans own just 15.6% of America 's wealth. The number of
people who slipped into poverty in 2010 was at an all time high of 46.2
million, so the poorest 20% of all Americans, in terms of wealth ownership,
includes 15.5 million who are technically above the income poverty line. The
poorest 40% of Americans essentially own almost nothing while the top 20% own almost 85% of everything. As a result, favorable
tax policies for capital gains income has a highly disproportional benefit for
the wealthiest Americans. Capital income for this wealthy segment is what drives rising income inequality today.
___________________________________________________________________________
Changes in
Income Inequality Among U.S. Tax Filers
Between 1991 and 2006: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes
Thomas L. Hungerford
thunger@starpower.net
Electronic
copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207372
HIGHLIGHTS FROM THIS REPORT:
Research has demonstrated that
large income and class disparities adversely affect health and economic
well-being (see, for example, Marmot 2004, Wilkinson 1996, Frank 2007, Singh
and Siahpush 2006).
Research has shown, however,
that income mobility [in the United States ] is not very great and the
degree of income mobility has either remained unchanged or decreased since the 1970’s
(Hungerford 2011, and Bradbury 2011).
Earnings inequality has been
increasing since at least the late-1960s (Kopczuk, Saez, and Song 2010). [The] CBO
(2011) has documented that income inequality has been increasing in the United States over the past 35 years.
Three potential causes of the
increase in after-tax income inequality between 1991 and 2006 are examined in
the analysis: changes in labor income (wages and salaries), changes in capital
income (interest income, capital gains, dividends, and business income), and
changes in taxes.
Increased salaries paid to CEOs,
managers, financial professionals, and athletes, is estimated to account for 70
percent of the increase in the share of income going to the richest Americans
(Bakija, Cole, and Heim 2010).
A declining real minimum wage
could affect lower income tax filers (the inflation-adjusted minimum wage fell
from $6.57 per hour in 1996 to $5.57 per hour in 2006).
Income of the richest 0.1
percent of taxpayers is sensitive to changes in asset prices and this may have
been especially important in the increase in the
income share of those at the top
of the income distribution (Bakija, Cole, and Heim 2010).
Frabdorf, Grabker, and Schwarze
(2011) also find that capital income’s share in disposable income has increased
in recent years in the U.S. and show that capital income made a large contribution
to income inequality in relation to its share in income.
While the individual income tax
system is progressive and has been since it was introduced in 1913, the trend
has been toward lower marginal tax rates and a less progressive tax system
(Piketty and Saez 2007, and Alm, Lee, and Wallace 2005). As a result, the tax
system may be less able to equalize after-tax incomes.
The major tax changes between
1991 and 2006 were (1) the enactment of the Omnibus Budget and Reconciliation
Act of 1993 (OBRA93), which increased the top marginal tax rate from 31 percent
to 39.6 percent, and (2) the enactment of the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts,
which reduced taxes especially for higher-income tax filers. The Bush tax cuts
involved reduced tax rates, the introduction of the 10 percent tax bracket
(which reduced taxes for all taxpayers), [it also] reduced the tax rates on
long-term capital gains and qualified dividends. In 1991, long-term capital
gains were taxed at 28 percent (15 percent for lower-income taxpayers) and all
dividends were taxed as ordinary income. The next year, the
long-term capital gains tax rate
was reduced to 20 percent. By 2006, long-term capital gains and qualified
dividends were taxed at 15 percent (5 percent for lower-income taxpayers). Tax
policy changes that affect progressivity will affect after-tax income
inequality (Kim and Lambert 2009, and Hungerford 2010).
Hungerford (2010) notes,
however, that about 75 percent of families contain just one tax unit (another
17 percent contain two tax units with the second tax unit usually a
cohabitating adult or a working child that cannot be claimed as
a dependent on another tax
return). Consequently, most of the tax units likely represent a family.
Piketty and Saez (2003) argue
that capital gains are not an annual flow of income and have large aggregate
variations from one year to another; they exclude capital gains from much of
their analysis. Blinder (1980) argues that capital gains should not be included
in income because what is important is real accrued capital gains [cashed out]. Also, that capital gains represents partial
maintenance of in an inflationary world. [in other words, gains shouldn’t be
taxed as it serves as an inflation adjustment for capital]
A stock option is reported on a
tax return as wages and salaries when it is exercised, but when the stock is
sold, any gain is reported as capital gains.
capitals gains have increasingly
become an important source of compensation
for corporate executives
(through stock options), and private equity and hedge fund managers (carried
interests). Consequently, income from capital gains is included in the
analysis.
Several recent studies estimate
that most or all (in some cases more than 100
percent) of the burden of the
corporate income tax falls on labor through reduced wages while other evidence
suggests that most or all of the burden of the corporate income tax falls on
owners of capital. [So take your pick!]
Federal individual and corporate
income taxes had an equalizing effect on inequality regardless of the
inequality measure. Federal taxes had a slightly greater equalizing effect in
2006 than in 1991—taxes appear to have been slightly more progressive in 2006
than in 1991. The top marginal tax rate in 1991 was 31 percent compared to 35 percent
in 2006; the lowest tax marginal rate was 15 percent in 1991 and 10 percent in
2006. However, the increased equalizing effect of the individual income tax is
likely due to bracket creep—more income is taxed at the highest rates—than to
tax law changes. Tax policy changes appear to have played a direct role: OBRA93
tended to have an equalizing effect on after-tax income while the 2001 and 2003
Bush tax cuts tended to have a disequalizing effect.
Tax policy may have also have
had an indirect effect on rising income inequality, especially between 2001 and
2006. The reduction in the tax rate on long-term capital gains and qualified
dividends may have led to the increased importance of this source in after-tax
income.
Overall, changes in [wage] labor
income does not appear to be a significant source of increased income
inequality between 1991 and 2006. Wages had no or a small disequalizing effect
when other inequality measures are used.
By far, the largest contributor
to increasing income inequality (regardless of income inequality measure) was
changes in income from capital gains and dividends. Capital gains and dividends
were less equally distributed in 1991 than in 2006, though highly unequally
distributed in both years.
Thomas L. Hungerford
currently works at the Congressional Research Service (CRS) which is part of
the Library of Congress. The CRS
provides the policy and legal analysis to Congressional committees and Members,
regardless of their party affiliation. CRS staffers sometimes do reports on
their own. Hungerford says this report, “… [does] not reflect the views of the Congressional
Research Service or the Library of Congress.”
Hungerford is well-published in the professional literature. He has worked for the Social Security
Administration, the Office of Management and Budget, and the General Accounting
Office in the past. The excerpts highlighted
here are of my own. You are encouraged
to read the full study at the URL address provide above.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Please feel free to comment or make suggestions